Improving Financial Reporting

Balancing statutory and common law approaches

At least since the introduction of federal securities laws in the U.S. some eighty years ago, attempts to regulation financial reporting have become increasingly focused on writing down the rules of accounting in ever-increasing detail. This codification or statutory approach to accounting regulation has marginalized the earlier dominance of a "common law" approach to accounting in which managers, accountants, and auditors used their best judgments to decide what to report, and how to report it. "True-and-fair" was the accounting equivalent of the "guilty-beyond-reasonable-doubt" standard still used by lay juries in courts of law to make life-and-death decisions. In pursuit of faux objectivity, accounting regulators around the world, including the U.S. and the European Union, have strayed after being persuaded that writing thousands of pages of rules by bureaucracies with monopoly power will serve us better. Nothing could be farther from the truth.

Unfortunately, there is little evidence that all these rules (mislabeled as standards for marketing purposes) have helped improve the quality of financial reporting. On the contrary, there is plenty of evidence that the standards written by the US and European bodies (FASB and IASB respectively) contributed to the recent global financial crisis at its roots. To consider two examples, replacement of lower-of-cost-or-market by mark-to-mark accounting (under comforting but misleading label of fair value accounting) substituted accounting for markets by accounting from markets. With accounting simply reflecting what was happening in security markets, such reports ceased to provide the markets with any independent information, making the accounting-market system a hall-of-mirrors, just reflecting one another. The world economy has paid dearly for the resultant indeterminacy and instability in markets.

In a second example, rule makers allowed banks to delay recognition of losses on their loans until specific defaulters become known to the banks. They ignored the long-standing practice of recognizing certain amount of loss at origination of loans because, it is virtually certain that among the borrowers from any bank holding a loan portfolio, a subset will default at some point of time. By delaying the recognition of loan losses, the rule-makers allowed banks to overstate their earnings, and to pay out handsome bonuses to their executives from profits that were never realized.

A good financial reporting system requires a careful balance between an economical set of written general principles (think Ten Commandments, not IASB's 3,000+ pages of what they claim are "principles-based standards") and professional judgment guided by true-and-fair criterion. What is true-and-fair in financial reporting will be judged by common sense-based on considerations of equity; we already know, through experience of the recent decades, that writing out more details into the rulebook creates more loopholes than it closes.

Financial engineering and financial reporting

Unlike most other industries, assets in financial services industry have no physical substance; they are defined by their accounting and covenants. This is true of shares of stock, bonds, and derivative securities. The specific combination of covenants and accounting features that define a security are designed by financial engineers (FE). FEs cohabit the world of financial reporting along with managers, bankers, traders, and accountants, and design the securities and transactions to achieve the goals of the clients they work for. If the client is an investment banker, they may design a security so it is attractive to some class of buyers, but has sufficient complexity to allow the banker to sell it for more than it is worth. If the client is a business corporation, they may design the security to help the corporation raise financing without increasing its leverage or risk exposure as reflected in its financial reports under the prevailing rules of accounting. In other words, the primary function of financial engineering is to manage appearances and to mislead. In this sense, creativity in finance is no different from, or better than, creativity in accounting; the latter is often condemned, but the realization that the former has similar consequences is not yet widespread.

Financial engineers have two advantages over accountants. First, accountants must do accounting for whatever transactions their clients choose to engage in; they have no say on their clients' choice of transactions. Financial engineers, on the other hand, have no constraints on what kinds of transactions they can create to serve their clients. Second, while accountants may take years of discussion and due process to write the rules of accounting for a given kind of transaction, it takes financial engineers little time "as little as days or hours "to design the transactions and securities that may serve their goals.

Massive expansion of written accounting rules over the recent decades (by the FASB as well as the IASB) has been driven by an unwise and futile attempts by accounting regulators to fend off the innovations of financial engineers through increasing codification. Accountants do not seem to have realized that this strategy makes them sitting ducks for, and guaranteed losers to, financial engineers. Accountants foolishly respond to financial engineering "innovations" by writing more detailed rules to "clarify" the existing rules. Every clarification serves as a roadmap for evasion for the financial engineers because the additional detail makes it easier for them to design new securities and transactions to achieve their aims of frustrating the intent of accounting regulators. This is not a winnable game for accounting regulators. What could be an alternative strategy?

An open, not a closed system of financial reporting

Accounting regulators have fallen victim to financial engineering in a trap of their own making. How can they escape, and improve the quality of financial reporting? They allowed themselves to be persuaded by self-interested sweet talk about a "single set of high quality accounting standards enforced world-wide" improving the quality and comparability of financial reporting. What is "high quality" in standards remains undefined; and application of same standards across industries or countries has not enhanced comparability. Yet, accounting regulators granted monopoly jurisdictions to FASB in the US and to IASB in EU. Then they proceeded to attempt a world-wide monopoly by agreeing to form a cartel and pursue a convergence project. This has been a disaster for three reasons.

Nobody knows, experts included, which proposed accounting rules will prove to be "good" or "bad", or even what their consequences would be when they are put in practice. Several decades of evidence on actions of the FASB and the IASB confirms our state of ignorance. The financial reporting, investment, market, and broader economic environment is simply too complex for even the best set of unbiased, selfless, hardworking people to accurately figure out the consequences of new accounting regulations. Though a washing machine is a far simpler mechanism, no manufacturer would dream of making and selling a new design without subjecting it to a field test. Yet, the power of monopoly rights granted to them gave the FASB and IASB sufficient confidence in their wisdom so they implemented and enforced many new accounting rules without any attempt to test them in the field. The results of their missteps (see mark-to-market accounting above) contributed to the global financial crisis.

Evolution of a complex socio-economic system calls for learning from trial and error. Granting a monopoly makes it difficult to conduct such experiments, and to compare the consequences of alternative accounting regimes. Imagine a world in which all listed companies in the world had to use the accounting rules written by a single body (e.g., IFRS). It would be impossible, in such a world, to find better accounting systems through research and comparison of alternatives. As economics tells us, most costly consequence of monopoly is loss of information available from competition. Absent competition, accounting too is essentially frozen, and unable to deal with the changing environment, and fast-moving financial engineering.

Instead, it would make a lot more sense to create an open system for accounting regulation by each jurisdiction selecting two or more rule-making bodies whose standards are permitted to be used by entities in the jurisdiction. The US, for example, could permit (if it considered them appropriate) its companies to prepare their financial reports using accounting rules written by, say, the FASB, the IASB, and the Japanese rule-makers. Companies will be required to pay royalties to the body whose standards they use, and these royalties will be the sole source of their income. Rule-makers will receive no funding from governments, and will be monitored on an annual basis by the governments to assess which standards should be allowed in their jurisdiction. Such a competitive arrangement for standards has the advantage of forcing the rule makers to balance the interests of investors, companies and the public. They will be induced to compare their rules with alternatives and adjust them to find a better balance between their detail and generality. Investors can be expected to flee from investment in companies who choose "cheap" standards, thus preventing a race to the bottom. Such regulatory competition is common in all parts of the world in education, insurance, corporate charters, stock exchanges, and environmental regulation. There is no reason why accountants cannot use a similar approach to escape the trap of financial engineering in which they have been caught by their pursuit of increasingly detailed written rules.

Academic Research as Unfiltered Water

Contents of our research journals are like unfiltered water. Decision and policy makers should stand forewarned before they use the contents of academic journals to guide them in their work. Fortunately, most of them maintain a healthy skeptical attitude to our findings and prescriptions until they have more evidence on their efficacy.

This is not to minimize the labor of editors and referees who spend months scrutinizing scholarly work for shortcomings before allowing it to be published in journals. This work may be necessary but rarely sufficient to prepare new ideas and research findings to be put to actual use. The editorial process is already quite arduous, and making it  longer will add more delay before new ideas can be disseminated for broader discussion and evaluation.

Scholarly scrutiny is based on scholarly knowledge with its own limitations. There is much about the world that even the most knowledgeable person does not know. Full consequences of most, if not all, research reports cannot be known until they go through a much longer process of filtration at multiple levels. This can take years, even decades. Only a small fraction of new ideas survive this lengthy scrutiny and experience through trials in the field. When they do, we have greater confidence that the results of putting them into practice have a lower chance of yielding a surprise.

Research findings published in academic journals rarely have had the opportunity to be filtered by experience, robustness, and common sense. Researchers, public relations offices of universities and corporations, as well as the mass media have all the incentives to pronounce on the practical implications of new findings from academic research way before these findings are ready for the prime time. It is only an aggressive decision maker who jumps at such announcements without allowing for the fact that research journals are forums for proposing new ideas that show some initial promise; some good ideas are mixed in with a lot of bad ones in this offering. Temptation to get a jump on the competition, being photographed for the newspapers and testifying in Congress is high for those willing to take the risk of being proved wrong.

The recent brouhaha about the Reinhard and Rogoff research paper is hardly a unique example. Computational errors are not that uncommon. But given time, they have a better chance of being caught and rectified before they do much damage. The story may be remembered more for the consequences of the alacrity in incorporating unfiltered academic research into public policy.

Pakistan's population up by 46.9 per cent since 1998

On March 30, 2012, the Dawn reported that Pakistan's population increased by 46.9 percent between 1998 and 2011.

India's officially counted populations in 2011 is more than 4 times its population at the time of independence in 1947. And some Indians think that Indian population may be 1.5 instead of 1.2 billion due to under counting. On top of that, even well-informed and well-meaning people in India often talk about "population dividend" from a large proportion of population being young, albeit uneducated and unskilled. This would seem like living in la-la land, cleaning the beaches while the tsunami is on the horizon. But nobody likes people who go around warning "the sky is falling." People use their considerable intelligence to find rationalizations until it is too late. That, I think, is the tragedy of social sciences. In spite of all the professed rationality and spirituality in India, ultimately, it is Charvaka's Lokayata philosophy: "yaawat jeevait, sukham jeevait; rinam kritwa, ghritam pibet" (as long as you live, live in luxury; borrow money, and enjoy life) "at least for the current generations. How else do we explain the European and U.S. financial crisis?

The crisis has its roots in the moral foundations of our civilization (reproduction, preservation of life, and consumption as treasured values). It worked until Louis Pasteur disturbed the balance between life and death. China (the only country that has done something deliberately in the policy field to address the issue through its one-child policy) is condemned on moral grounds, while we merrily rush towards starvation, pestilence, war, and annihilation. Here faith in God (He has made us all, he will provide for us) is a problem.